51 Present and future value
Comparison is an important element of human decision making. Often, comparison amounts to translating each of the options at hand into a scalar score. (Recall that a scalar is just an ordinary quantity, e.g. 73 inches. As we get more deeply involved with vectors it will become more important to be perfectly clear when we are talking about a vector and when about a scalar. So we will be using “scalar” a lot.) Scalars are easy to compare; the skill is taught in elementary school. Scalar comparison is completely objective. Putting aside the possibility of error, everyone will agree on which of two numbers is bigger. Importantly, comparison of scalars is transitive, that is if
The comparison of scalars can be extended to situations where the options available form a continuum and the score for each option
Many decisions involve options that have two or more attributes that are not directly comparable. Expenditure decisions have this flavor: Is it worth the money to buy a more reliable or prettier or more capable version of a product? The techniques of constrained optimization (Chapter 49) provide one useful approach for informing decisions when there are multiple objectives.
Elections are a form of collective decision making. The options—called, of course, “candidates”—have many attributes. Three such attitudes are attitudes toward social policy, toward fiscal policy, and toward foreign policy. Perceived honesty and trustworthiness as well as the ability to influence other decision makers and perceived ability to win the election are other attributes that are considered and balanced against one another. Ultimately the decision is made by condensing the diverse attributes into a single choice for each voter. The election is decided by how many votes the candidate garners. With this number attached to each of the candidates, it is easy to make the decision,
This chapter is about a very common situation where there are multiple attributes that need to be condensed into a single score. The setting is simple: money. The question is how to condense a future income/expense stream—a function of time—into an equivalent value of money in hand at the present. This is called the present value problem. There is a solution to the problem that is widely accepted as valid, just as voting is a hallowed process of social optimization. But like voting, with its multiplicity of possible forms, there is a subtlety that renders the result somewhat arbitrary. This is not a situation where there is a single, mathematically correct answer but rather a mathematical framework for coming to sensible conclusions.
51.1 Present value
People and institutions often have to make decisions about undertakings where the costs and benefits are spread out over time. For instance, a person acquiring an automobile or home is confronted with a large initial outlay. The outlay can be financed by agreeing to pay amounts in the future, often over a span of many years.
Another example: Students today are acutely aware of climate change and the importance of taking preventive or mitigating actions such as discouraging fossil fuel production, investing in renewable sources of energy and the infrastructure for using them effectively, and exploring active measures such as carbon sequestration. The costs and benefits of such actions are spread out over decades, with the costs coming sooner than the benefits. Policy makers are often and perhaps correctly criticized for overvaluing present-day costs and undervaluing benefits that accrue mainly to successive generations. There are many analogous situations on a smaller scale, such as setting Social Security taxes and benefits or the problem of underfunded pension systems and the liability for pension payments deferred to future taxpayers.
The conventional mechanism for condensing an extended time stream of benefits and costs is called discounting. Discounting is based on the logic of financing expenditures via borrowing at interest. For example, credit cards are a familiar mechanism for financing purchases by delaying the payment of money until the future. An expense that is too large to bear is “carried” on a credit card so that it can be paid off as funds become available in the future. This incurs costs due to interest on the credit-card balance. Typical credit-card interest rates are 18-30% per year.
As notation, consider a time stream of income
The big conceptual leap is to understand that the present value of income in a future time is less than the same amount of income at the present time. In other words, we discount future money compared to present money. For example, if we decide that an amount of money that becomes available 10 years into the future is worth only half as much as that same amount of money if it were available today, we would be implying a discounting to 50%. In comparison, if that money were available 20 years in the future, it would make sense to discount it by more strongly to, say, 25%.
To represent the discounting to present value as it might vary with the future time horizon, we multiply the nominal income stream
The net present value (NPV) of a nominal income stream
51.2 Discounting functions
What should be the shape of the discounting function?
Recall that the purpose of the discounting function is to help us make comparisons between different income streams, that is, between the various options available to an entrepreneur. Each individual can in principle have his or her own, personal discounting function, much as each voter is entirely free to weight the different attributes of the candidates when deciding whom to vote for. As a silly example, a person might decide that money that comes in on a Tuesday is lucky and therefore worth more than Thursday money. We won’t consider such personalized forms further and instead emphasize discounting functions that reflect more standard principles of finance and economics.
As a thought experiment, consider the net present value of an income stream, that is
- Simply discount the original NPV to account for it becoming available
years in the future, that is, - Apply to
a discount that takes into account the -year delay. That is:
For (1) and (2) to be the same, we need to restrict the form of so that The form of function that satisfies this restriction is the exponential, that is .
51.3 Compound interest
A more down-to-earth derivation of the form of
For this proposition to be attractive to you, the present value of
If you were to borrow money for two years, the bank would presumably want to charge more for the loan. A typical practice is to charge compound interest. Compound interest corresponds to treating the loan as having two phases: first, borrow one dollar for a year and owe
51.4 Mortgages
A mortgage is a form of loan where you pay back the borrowed amount at a steady rate, month by month. At the end of a specified period, called the term of the mortgage, your have completely discharged the debt.
Suppose you decide to buy a product that costs
Your plan is to pay an amount
You can put the purchase on your credit card at an interest rate of
The loan will be in balance if the net present value of the payments is the same as the amount